Author Topic: Election Day USA  (Read 6758 times)

0 Members and 1 Guest are viewing this topic.

Offline Goober5000

  • HLP Loremaster
  • 214
    • Goober5000 Productions
It's amazing how quick people are to hand power back to the morons who got us into this whole mess
At what point were the bankers stripped of their power?

 

Offline Sushi

  • Art Critic
  • 211
Both parties have mostly sucky ideas and both have abysmal implementation.

FTFY

 

Offline Klaustrophobia

  • 210
  • the REAL Nuke of HLP
    • North Carolina Tigers
i wonder why i even bother reading threads like this.
I like to stare at the sun.

 

Offline Bobboau

  • Just a MODern kinda guy
    Just MODerately cool
    And MODest too
  • 213
You really think it'll matter which letter winds up winning out the night?  We're equally ****ed regardless. I suggest the Nuke Plan. :D

ah, so you mean the teabaggers-get-elected plan? looks like that's got some momentum.
Bobboau, bringing you products that work... in theory
learn to use PCS
creator of the ProXimus Procedural Texture and Effect Generator
My latest build of PCS2, get it while it's hot!
PCS 2.0.3


DEUTERONOMY 22:11
Thou shalt not wear a garment of diverse sorts, [as] of woollen and linen together

 

Offline Mongoose

  • Rikki-Tikki-Tavi
  • Global Moderator
  • 212
  • This brain for rent.
    • Steam
    • Something
Hey, at least Ms. Witch lost big.  That's something. :p

 

Offline MP-Ryan

  • Makes General Discussion Make Sense.
  • Global Moderator
  • 210
  • Keyboard > Pen > Sword
It's amazing how quick people are to hand power back to the morons who got us into this whole mess
At what point were the bankers stripped of their power?

Ahem - it was economic policy put in place by de-regulation at the hands of the GOp that enabled them to cause the mess.  Let's not kid ourselves - the US government had a massive role in precipitating the financial crash through inaction.

Countries with financial regulation that hadn't been gutted by ideologues have weathered the recession quite well - in some cases, without losing a single major financial institution.  The US was hit hardest for two reasons:
1.  It had some of the largest financial institutions.
2.  Those institutions were permitted to engage in financial practices that were essentially guaranteed to collapse on the system.

Warnings went out on the sub-prime mortgage fiasco in general as far back as 2005 - and were promptly ignored by the Republican-dominated chambers and President.

Ideology - the same one that just got elected in majority to the House of Representatives - is what got us all into this mess.  Democrat, Republican, it doesn't matter - the neo-conservative taxes-and-government-are-bad mentality without an ounce of common sense created the problem, and I don't see the same policies re-enacted fixing it anytime soon.

That said, the US system of governance is designed to function best with different groups holding sway in the different levels of government, so it's probably a good thing that the Democrats lost their majority in the House.
"In the beginning, the Universe was created.  This made a lot of people very angry and has widely been regarded as a bad move."  [Douglas Adams]

 

Offline Goober5000

  • HLP Loremaster
  • 214
    • Goober5000 Productions
Ahem - it was economic policy put in place by de-regulation at the hands of the GOp that enabled them to cause the mess.  Let's not kid ourselves - the US government had a massive role in precipitating the financial crash through inaction.
Let's concede your argument about deregulation for the moment.  Do you then say that the bankers bear absolutely no blame for the actions that followed?  If there are two ways to take advantage of deregulation -- one positive way, with integrity, and one selfish way, with greed and short-sightedness -- and if a banker chooses greed over integrity, is he completely innocent?  Even if he willfully chooses to enrich himself, his colleagues, and his profession at the expense of the economy and the general population?

 

Offline Bob-san

  • Wishes he was cool
  • 210
  • It's 5 minutes to midnight.
You really think it'll matter which letter winds up winning out the night?  We're equally ****ed regardless. I suggest the Nuke Plan. :D

ah, so you mean the teabaggers-get-elected plan? looks like that's got some momentum.
The tea party movement's elections were not absolute but they're again a step in the right direction. Like it or not, conservatives and libertarians and Christians are all parts of America and everyone over 18 has the right to vote. They got elected over incumbents and competitors. If their policies will be good and in-line with with their electors want when in office, they'll be reelected. Otherwise, if people are dissatisfied, they'll be voted out of office like the incumbent before them. They should have just as much say as everyone else, regardless if you love or abhor their policies and their campaigns.
« Last Edit: November 04, 2010, 11:11:45 am by Bob-san »
NGTM-1R: Currently considering spending the rest of the day in bed cuddling.
GTSVA: With who...?
Nuke: chewbacca?
Bob-san: The Rancor.

 

Offline MR_T3D

  • 29
  • Personal Text
Ahem - it was economic policy put in place by de-regulation at the hands of the GOp that enabled them to cause the mess.  Let's not kid ourselves - the US government had a massive role in precipitating the financial crash through inaction.
Let's concede your argument about deregulation for the moment.  Do you then say that the bankers bear absolutely no blame for the actions that followed?  If there are two ways to take advantage of deregulation -- one positive way, with integrity, and one selfish way, with greed and short-sightedness -- and if a banker chooses greed over integrity, is he completely innocent?  Even if he willfully chooses to enrich himself, his colleagues, and his profession at the expense of the economy and the general population?
I thought ryan was still blaming both, but bankers aren't innocent, they ****ed things up, but the GOP gave them the tools to do so, kind of like gun violence.
you're taking the 'guns don't kill people' route as opposed to the 'because they have guns they're able to kill people', the truth is somewhere in between, and in my opinion, it is more the fault of government de-regualtion, because it lets them do it, you can't just trust everyone to be selfless, unfortunately.
however, gov't regulation is the easier way to 'fix' stuff without the gov't going into the banks and firing dudes.

 

Offline iamzack

  • 26
You really think it'll matter which letter winds up winning out the night?  We're equally ****ed regardless. I suggest the Nuke Plan. :D

ah, so you mean the teabaggers-get-elected plan? looks like that's got some momentum.
The tea party movement's elections were not absolute but they're again a step in the right direction. Like it or not, conservatives and libertarians and Christians are all parts of America and everyone over 18 has the right to vote. They got elected over incumbents and competitors. If their policies will be good and in-line with with their electors want when in office, they'll be reelected. Otherwise, if people are dissatisfied, they'll be voted out of office like the incumbent before them. They should have just as much say as everyone else, regardless if you love or abhor their policies and their campaigns.

They have more say than everyone else. That's where the problem lies.
WE ARE HARD LIGHT PRODUCTIONS. YOU WILL LOWER YOUR FIREWALLS AND SURRENDER YOUR KEYBOARDS. WE WILL ADD YOUR INTELLECTUAL AND VERNACULAR DISTINCTIVENESS TO OUR OWN. YOUR FORUMS WILL ADAPT TO SERVICE US. RESISTANCE IS FUTILE.

 

Offline General Battuta

  • Poe's Law In Action
  • 214
  • i wonder when my postcount will exceed my iq
You really think it'll matter which letter winds up winning out the night?  We're equally ****ed regardless. I suggest the Nuke Plan. :D

ah, so you mean the teabaggers-get-elected plan? looks like that's got some momentum.
The tea party movement's elections were not absolute but they're again a step in the right direction. Like it or not, conservatives and libertarians and Christians are all parts of America and everyone over 18 has the right to vote. They got elected over incumbents and competitors. If their policies will be good and in-line with with their electors want when in office, they'll be reelected. Otherwise, if people are dissatisfied, they'll be voted out of office like the incumbent before them. They should have just as much say as everyone else, regardless if you love or abhor their policies and their campaigns.

Well...voter decisions don't have much to do with policies. Most citizens aren't even aware of the policies, even in this day and age. I've been working with data sets on this topic for the past couple weeks. Things are not exactly bleak for democracy, but they're pretty ambivalent.

 

Offline Bob-san

  • Wishes he was cool
  • 210
  • It's 5 minutes to midnight.
You really think it'll matter which letter winds up winning out the night?  We're equally ****ed regardless. I suggest the Nuke Plan. :D

ah, so you mean the teabaggers-get-elected plan? looks like that's got some momentum.
The tea party movement's elections were not absolute but they're again a step in the right direction. Like it or not, conservatives and libertarians and Christians are all parts of America and everyone over 18 has the right to vote. They got elected over incumbents and competitors. If their policies will be good and in-line with with their electors want when in office, they'll be reelected. Otherwise, if people are dissatisfied, they'll be voted out of office like the incumbent before them. They should have just as much say as everyone else, regardless if you love or abhor their policies and their campaigns.

They have more say than everyone else. That's where the problem lies.

So go start up your own movement and try to get elected in 2012. There are 300 million people in this country and about 80% of them are over 18. Your one vote can neutralize one Tea Party vote, so get out there and make your own difference. Right or wrong, everyone has their own vote and most everyone has the right to exercise that vote.

The problem I see here is the same as before; so many people scream insults at so-called loud-mouthed morons.

@Battuta: Voter decisions choose broad policies and express dissent when policies are not to their liking. As a perfect example, take a look at the last 2 years of Obama's presidency and the final 2 years of Bush's presidency. Bush was reelected and hit a term limit. Neither he nor Chaney were impeached. Obama and a wider Democratic majority was voted in. All it'd take to pass a super-majority would be to convince ONE Republican to vote for their policy. In my opinion, that was the perfect time for the Democrats to show that they can truly work with the opposite side for the good of the country. And, on occasion, they did.

Just as Obama campaigned on "Change", the GOP won this midterm election on "Change".
NGTM-1R: Currently considering spending the rest of the day in bed cuddling.
GTSVA: With who...?
Nuke: chewbacca?
Bob-san: The Rancor.

 

Offline General Battuta

  • Poe's Law In Action
  • 214
  • i wonder when my postcount will exceed my iq
Quote
@Battuta: Voter decisions choose broad policies and express dissent when policies are not to their liking. As a perfect example, take a look at the last 2 years of Obama's presidency and the final 2 years of Bush's presidency. Bush was reelected and hit a term limit. Neither he nor Chaney were impeached. Obama and a wider Democratic majority was voted in. All it'd take to pass a super-majority would be to convince ONE Republican to vote for their policy. In my opinion, that was the perfect time for the Democrats to show that they can truly work with the opposite side for the good of the country. And, on occasion, they did.

Cite your data set, please. This is just an amateur talking out of his ass. I'm sitting on mountains of MIT data here and there are three profs working on the topic literally five steps away from my desk.

Here, I've got something for you to read.

Code: [Select]
Retrospective voting is central to theorizing about democracy . Given voters' ignorance about politics and public policy, some argue that it is democracy's best defense. This defense, however, assumes citizens are competent evaluators of incumbent politicians' performance. Although little research has investigated this assumption, voters' retrospective assessments in a key domain, the economy, appear flawed. They overweight election-year income growth in presidential elections, ignoring cumulative growth under the incumbent. In this paper, I present evidence that this myopia arises from a more general "end bias" in retrospective assessments. Using a three-year panel survey, I show that citizens' memories of the past economy are inconsistent with their actual experience of the economy as they reported it in earlier interviews. They fail to remember the past correctly in part because the present shapes their perceptions of the past. I then show similar behavior in the lab. When participants evaluate economic and crime data, I again find that election-year performance shapes perceptions of overall performance, even under conditions where the election year should not be more informative. Finally, I search for and appear to find a cure. Presenting participants with cumulative information on performance (e.g., total income growth or total rise in murders during incumbents’ terms) cures this myopia. On one hand, these results are troubling for democracy because they confirm citizens’ incompetence at retrospection. On the other hand, they point to a remedy, one that candidates and the news media could adopt.






I thank Paco Flores-Macias, Mike Myers, and Michael Peress for helpful comments and suggestions, as well as seminar participants at MIT and Yale University.
 

The first systematic investigations of citizens' knowledge about politics revealed a bleak picture (Berelson, Lazarsfeld, and McPhee 1954; Campbell et al. 1960). In their landmark study, Berelson, Lazarsfeld, and McPhee (1954), for instance, assessed citizens' awareness of the two most prominent public policy issues in the 1948 presidential election campaign, issues on which Truman and Dewey, the Democratic and Republican presidential candidates, disagreed. These issues were government policy towards labor unions (Taft-Hartley) and price controls. According to Lazarsfeld and his colleagues, Truman's and Dewey's differences on these two issues were “reasonably straightforward and clear” and were “crucial issues in the campaign, much discussed in the communication media” (Berelson, Lazarsfeld, and McPhee 1954, 227-28). Nonetheless, their survey found a pervasive ignorance about Truman's and Dewey's positions: only 16 percent of their sample knew both candidates' positions on both issues.
Numerous studies have confirmed this lack of political knowledge among the public (Delli Carpini and Keeter 1996; Zaller 1992). To provide a more recent example, only 55 percent of citizens in 2004 saw Kerry and the Democratic Party as more supportive of abortion rights than they saw Bush and the Republican Party, a percentage probably inflated by guessing.
Given voter ignorance, researchers turned to retrospective voting as an explanation for democracy's success (Fiorina 1981; Key 1968; Kramer 1971). Democracy may work despite this ignorance, these scholars argued, because citizens can judge politicians retrospectively on their performance. They can simply ask, are we better off than we were four years ago? Are we losing a war? Has our standing in the world improved?
This retrospective solution to the democratic dilemma, however, assumes citizens are competent evaluators of performance. Although little research has investigated this assumption, evidence suggests that, at least on the economy, voters' assessments are flawed. They appear to judge incumbents myopically, focusing mostly on election-year income growth, not cumulative growth. Numerous studies have documented the importance of election-year income growth (e.g., Kramer 1971), though interpreting it as myopic is recent (Achen and Bartels 2004; Bartels 2008). Presidents, the data indicate, can preside over poor economic conditions for much of their terms and still win reelection, as long as the economy grows in the months before Election Day.
The myopic tendencies of citizens have profound implications for public policy. Most importantly, they create perverse incentives for presidents. To increase their chances of winning reelection, they may boost economic growth during election years, even at the cost of future growth. As Tufte (1978) writes, voters' short time horizons could produce "a bias toward policies with immediate, highly visible benefits and deferred, hidden costs ─ myopic policies for myopic voters." Evidence suggests that presidents enact precisely these sorts of policies with observable consequences: on average, real disposable income growth (RDI) is significantly higher during presidential election years (Achen and Bartels 2004; Bartels 2008).  By focusing on the election-year economy, voters may reelect presidents most willing to manipulate the economy (adverse selection), such as Richard Nixon (Tufte 1978), while suffering from the deadweight loss induced by wasteful government spending.
In this paper, I present evidence that myopic economic voting arises from a more general “end bias” in retrospective assessments, one that psychologists have documented in other domains (Ariely and Carmon 2000; Redelmeier and Kahneman 1996; Varey and Kahneman 1992). When citizens attempt to assess incumbent performance, their experiences at the end of terms appear to shape their memories of earlier performance. To support this claim, I present findings from panel surveys and experiments. Using panel data, I show that citizens' memories of the past economy are inconsistent with their actual experiences as they reported them in earlier interviews. They fail to remember the past correctly in part because the present shapes their perceptions of the past. In several experiments where participants evaluated hypothetical and real economic and crime data, I find the same end bias. Finally, I search for and appear to find a cure. Presenting participants with cumulative information on performance (e.g., total income growth or total rise in murders during incumbents’ terms) cures them of their myopia.
These results raise further concerns with retrospective voting as a defense of democracy, suggesting that citizens’ evaluations of incumbents may be flawed in domains other than just the economy. On the other hand, however, they point to a remedy, one that candidates and the news media could adopt.
Remembered versus experienced utility: end bias
In its simplest form, retrospective voting should be easy. As Fiorina (1981, 5) puts it, “[Citizens] need not know the precise economic or foreign policies of the incumbent administration in order to see or feel the results of those policies.  .  .  . In order to ascertain whether the incumbents have performed poorly or well, citizens need only calculate the changes in their own welfare.” Surprisingly, however, findings from psychology indicate that people often get these calculations wrong. The utility people experience in fact often diverges considerably from the utility they remember afterwards (Kahneman, Wakker, and Sarin 1997).
Instead of remembering overall utility, people attend to certain attributes, such as the peak pleasure or pain experienced, and neglect other attributes, such as duration (Ariely and Carmon 2000; Redelmeier and Kahneman 1996; Varey and Kahneman 1992). Of all the attributes, people most consistently attend to the end of experiences. Consider, for example, four dental treatments spaced over a week in which the intensity of pain either increases {2, 3, 4, 5} or decreases {5, 4, 3, 2}. Although individuals experienced the same total discomfort, retrospectively, they would remember the decreasing sequence as much less painful.
A series of experiments conducted by Varey and Kahneman (1992) provide a good example of this research. Participants began the studies by immersing one hand in very cold water for ten seconds. They were then told to expect three more trials of this kind, but only two were actually conducted. In the Short trial, participants kept one hand in water at 14°C for 60 seconds. In the Long trial the immersion lasted 90 seconds. Water temperature was kept at 14°C for the first 60 seconds, at which point the experimenter gradually raised the temperature from 14°C to 15°C over the next 30 seconds (unbeknownst to the participants). Half the participants experienced the Short trial before the Long one; the sequence was reversed for the other participants. After a seven minute delay, participants were called in for a third trial, informed that they would repeat one of the two previous procedures, given a choice of whether the first or the second trial should be repeated, and asked to answer several questions about the first two trials. Kahneman and his collaborators conducted several studies with this general design.
The results of these studies are striking. Even though participants experienced more total pain in the Long trial, they generally remembered it as less painful, and a large majority preferred to repeat the Long trial. The ever so slight decrease in pain experienced in the last 30 seconds of the Long trial led participants to remember it as less painful.
According to the researchers, post-experimental interviews and other observations provided no support for alternative explanations, such as a desire on the part of participants to endure more pain, experiencing the last segment of the Long trial as pleasurable (or not painful), experiencing the Long trial’s post-immersion as more pleasurable, or failing to remember its longer duration (most participants could correctly answer a question about the durations of the two trials). When they asked participants, in a separate study, to choose between hypothetical profiles of a Long and Short trial, participants invariably choose the Short trial.
Numerous studies document similar phenomena across a wide range of domains, including monetary payments (Loewenstein and Sicherman 1991), life experiences such as vacations (Loewenstein and Prelec 1991; Loewenstein and Prelec 1993), emotional episodes (Fredrickson and Kahneman 1993; Varey and Kahneman 1992), TV advertisements (Baumgartner, Sujan, and Padgett 1997), queuing experiences (Carmon and Kahneman 1996), pain (Ariely 1998; Ariely and Carmon 2000; Varey and Kahneman 1992), discomfort (Ariely and Zauberman 2000; Kahneman et al. 1993; Schreiber and Kahneman 2000), medical outcomes and treatments (Chapman 2000; Redelmeier and Kahneman 1996), gambling (Ross and Simonson 2006), and academic performance (Hsee, Abelson, and Salovey 1991; Zauberman, Diehl, and Ariely 2006).
The end of an experience not only shapes perceptions among those undergoing the experience, but also among observers, who exhibit the same biases. For example, in a study of colonoscopy patients, Redelmeier and Kahneman (1996) found that the peak pain and the pain experienced at the end of the procedure best predicted retrospective evaluations of colonoscopies’ painfulness, while the total pain experienced did not. After the procedures, researchers asked the administering physicians to rate each patients' overall discomfort. The physicians’ ratings evinced the same biases as the patients. Moreover, when asked which patients should have received more anesthetic, the doctors answered, not based on total pain, but on the peak and the end.
Observers also do not have to directly observe the experience to exhibit these biases. Varey and Kahneman (1992), for example, presented participants with a booklet containing discomfort ratings allegedly experienced by individuals as they underwent unpleasant experiences, such as listening to loud drilling noises. The booklet’s discomfort ratings, shown on a 10-point scale, differed in duration and in intensity over time, with each page showing a separate experience. After looking through the booklet, participants provided a global evaluation of each experience on a 0-100 scale. Even though participants did not directly observe the unpleasant episodes, they based their global evaluations primarily on the maximum and final intensities, with little weight on duration. For instance, participants rated the overall pain in the pain sequence {2, 5, 8} as worse than the overall pain in the sequence {2, 5, 8, 4), where larger numbers indicate more intense pain and each number represents the discomfort felt over a five-minute period. Based on these and other studies, observers thus appear to share the same biases in retrospective evaluations as those undergoing experiences. In particular, they both overweight the end.
Although coldwater immersion, colonoscopies, and loud drilling noises seem far afield from politicians’ performance, these studies suggest general biases in retrospection, especially end bias. Moreover, several studies find similar behavior in domains that more closely resemble politicians’ performance, such as evaluating factories’ production of defective products (reject rate) or tests of ability (Zauberman, Diehl, and Ariely 2006).
No consensus exists about the mechanism behind these biases, nor has much research investigated it. Nevertheless, these biases are consistent with a mechanism called attribute substitution (Kahneman 2003; Kahneman and Frederick 2002). When people attempt to judge a target attribute, such as the change in their welfare under an incumbent president, they search for a reasonable value. For some judgments, this search terminates almost immediately because the required value is readily accessible (e.g., the question “How old are you?”). For many judgments, however, the target attribute does not readily come to mind, but the search for it evokes other attributes that are related, such as “has my welfare improved this year.”  People then automatically substitute these related attributes for the target attribute. Given people's limited cognitive capacity and limited interest in politics, attribute substitution seems likely to occur when evaluating politicians’ performance.
Alternative explanations and diagnoses
A cognitive bias is, of course, not the only explanation for myopic economic voting. I briefly review two alternative explanations. An obvious one is that the last-year of incumbents' terms may be (or may seem) more informative. Since policies may take time to have their full effect, the last year may reveal the most about the incumbents' quality and may provide the best forecasts of second-term performance. Several facts, however, suggest that this explanation is either wrong or, if correct, the behavior itself is not optimal. In particular, the election-year economy does not in fact forecast the economy of the following four years when incumbents are retained (Achen and Bartels 2004).  Voters may, nevertheless, reasonably think that the fourth-year is more informative even if it is not. As I show below, however, survey and experimental evidence suggests they don't.
Another alternative arises from modeling of principle actor interactions. At times, principals (voters) may desire to incentivize actors (incumbents) to exert effort in the last period of multi-period game by committing to reward them if they do, even if the actors shirk in early periods. Bueno de Mesquita and Landa (2007) describe this as "What Have You Done For Me Lately" behavior. Although this should be explored further, it's not clear that citizens see an incumbent president’s four-year term as a multi-period game, at least with respect to the economy.
(Mis)Remembering your prior economic perceptions
President George H. W. Bush presided over a weak economy from late 1990 through until he faced reelection in 1992. In the three waves of the American National Election Study (ANES) Panel that cover this period (1990, 1991, and 1992), the percent seeing the economy as having gotten somewhat worse or much worse was 77 percent in 1990, 65 in 1991, and 72 in 1992. At the end of this panel (1992), the ANES did something rare. It asked about the economy over a period longer than a year. In addition to the usual one-year question, it asked about the previous four years. The exact wording was, “Compared to four years ago, would you say that the nation's economy has gotten [much/somewhat] better, stayed about the same, or gotten [much/somewhat] worse?”  
When people answered this question, did they actually consider what happened in earlier years? Or, did the end, in this case, 1992, shape their prior four-year retrospective evaluations? Since these responses were part of a panel survey, we can test whether people ignored their 1990 and 1991 perceptions, and primarily relied on their 1992 perceptions when answering the four-year question.
To measure economic perceptions in each year, the ANES question asks, “Has the nation's economy gotten [much/somewhat] better or [much/somewhat] worse or stayed the same in the past year?” For the analysis, I rescale all the variables to vary between 0 and 1. Table 1 presents the means and standard deviations of these variables.
Figure 1 provides suggestive evidence that people did focus more on 1992. It plots the average response to the four-year question against responses to the one-year questions in 1990, 1991, and 1992. The slope for 1992 is .49, about 150% larger than the slopes for 1990 and 1991, which are about .30.
People’s views about the economy in each year are probably correlated, making it difficult to know which year actually matters. To address this, I regress four-year evaluations on one-year evaluations. As Table 2 shows, the results even more clearly reveal the extent to which people either forget or down weight their responses in earlier years. The coefficients are .16, .12, and .43, for 1990-1992, respectively, which means 1992 receives about 300% more weight than the earlier years.
Moreover, these results do not appear to arise because of a general anti-Bush sentiment or partisanship that pervades responses in 1992. As the next column in Table 2 shows, the results hold when I control for party identification, Bush approval, an employed indicator, household income, married, education, political knowledge, and male, all measured in 1992. They also hold among just Democrats, just Republicans, and just independents (not shown). In short, these findings are consistent with end bias in retrospective evaluations of the economy, much like that shown in psychology studies.

Table 1: Average perceptions of the prior-year and four-year economies in the 1990-91-92 ANES Panel
 
 
 
Figure 1: When retrospectively evaluating the four-year economy in 1992, participants place more weight on 1992
This figure shows the average response to the four-year question against responses to the one-year questions in 1990, 1991, and 1992. The slope for 1992 is .49, about 150% larger than the slopes for 1990 and 1991, which are about .30.


Table 2: When retrospectively evaluating the four-year economy in 1992, participants place more weight on 1992
 
Column 5 includes the following additional controls (measured in 1992): PID, Bush approval, Unemployed indicator, Household income, Married, Education, Political knowledge, and Male.

Myopia also afflicts observers
If the end bias that psychologists have observed in other domains lies behind election-year retrospective economic voting, it should occur equally among people who actually experienced these economies and among observers. In this section, I test this prediction. I present the results of a series of studies where I showed participants economic and crime data. The experiments all had a similar design, one resembling psychology studies about end bias. In each, I showed participants bar plots of the yearly percent change in income or crime in each year of incumbents’ four-year terms. Participants saw between 15 and 25 such plots, each showing a four-year term, with the order of the terms randomized for each subject. In some of the studies, I generated the income and crime growth data by randomly drawing them from a normal distribution with a mean and variance chosen to match real-world data. In others, I use data from the historical record. Figure 2 presents two examples of these plots drawn from one study of the randomly drawn sort. In the first, the economy ends on a high note. In the second, it does not. Before showing the plots, participants read instructions that, in the economic cases, briefly explained income growth, mentioning that it was a good measure of the overall strength of the economy during a president's term, and noting that these data are either real or hypothetical. Below each plot, I asked them to evaluate the economy during the period shown. I recruited participants through a web service, paying them $.15-$.25.  Before analyzing the data, I drop participants who fail to evaluate each term and who fail a simple test of attention to the English instructions, usually about 10% of the samples.
End bias with randomly generated income growth — 2nd term presidents
In the first study, I showed participants 25 plots, with each displaying yearly income growth for a hypothetical presidents’ four-year term. To ensure that participants do not weight up later years because of beliefs about policy lags — first term presidents’ policies taking some time to kick in — I told participants that the plots showed economies under second term presidents.  I generated the yearly income growth data from a normal distribution with a mean and standard deviation equal to two, which is the average in the actual income data from 1947-2008. Below each plot, I asked, “How would you rate the condition of the national economy during this period? Is it very good, fairly good, fairly bad, or very bad?” To put income growth and these evaluations on a similar scale, I recoded responses to vary from 0 to 10, with 10 corresponding to “very good.” I take the average of the responses for each of the 25 terms and call this variable Economic evaluations.
Even though they are not directly experiencing these economies, and even with all four years in front of them, did participants still exhibit end bias in their retrospective evaluations? Figure 3 shows that they did. It plots participants’ average evaluation of the economy during the four-year periods against each year’s randomly generated income growth. When participants evaluate the economy, the figure shows, they pay almost no attention to growth in the first year (note the slightly negative slope), some weight to the second year, which has a positive slope, and considerable weight to the third and fourth years, with the fourth-year having the steepest positive slope and tightest fit. The fourth year slope is significantly larger than the third year or earlier years (ps <.01). So, even with all four years in front of them and even though they were told these were for a second term presidents, end bias emerges.





 

Figure 2: Examples of two plots shown to participants
Even though average income growth is higher in the economy shown in the bottom plot, 2.85%, than in the top plot, 2.60%, participants rated the economy on the top as stronger. On the 10-point scale, they rated the top as 9.1 on average and the bottom as only 6.3.
 
  
Figure 3: When evaluating the simulated four-year terms, participants focus more on the fourth year


To further explore these patterns, Table 3 presents regression estimates. In the first column, I regress the average evaluation on the income growth in each of the four years.  Controlling for income growth in each year changes the pattern of the coefficients slightly from that shown in Figure 3 (because of chance correlations between yearly growth), but the overall pattern remains the same. Participants place several times more weight on the last year (b = .61) than on the first year (b = .28) and all the estimates are statistically significant.
Participants’ retrospective evaluations of the plots in Figure 2 (page 9) illustrate this behavior. They rated the economy shown on the top of Figure 2, which ended well with 4.4% growth, as considerably better than the one at the bottom, which ended on a weak note, with only 1.7% growth. On the 10-point scale, they gave the figure on top an average of 9.1, but the bottom figure only 6.3. They did so even though the top figure has a higher overall average growth rate, 2.85% versus 2.60%, which is plainly visible to the eye.
The end bias findings on the economy appear robust. The results held when I reran the study with all aspects the same except I did not label the terms as second term (see Column 2, Table 3). They also held in additional studies with new sets of randomly drawn income data (see Column 3 and 4, Table 3). The final column of Table 3 presents the (precision weighted) average of all the studies. It shows that, on average, people place to 270% more weight on the fourth year than on the first year, and 155% more weight on the fourth-year than the third year. Both differences are highly statistically significant.


Table 3: When evaluating hypothetical income growth during four-year terms, participants exhibit end bias
Simulated economic data (25 four-year terms). Dependent variable: How would you rate the condition of the [national economy or state economy] during this period? Is it very good, fairly good, fairly bad, or very bad? To put income growth and these evaluations on a similar scale, I recoded responses to vary from 0 to 10, with 10 corresponding to “very good.” I take the average of the responses for each of the 25 terms, so the N for the regressions is 25 (a conservative approach to analysis). The precision weighted column average includes the studies from Columns 1-4 and from Table 7, Column 1.
DV: Four-year economic evaluations Replication
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Randomly drawn income data Same data as (1) Another random draw Another random draw Average (precision weighted)
Office President President President Governor All
Term Second Not specified All
Income growth %
    Year 1 0.28*** 0.22** 0.30*** 0.11 0.23***
(0.097) (0.083) (0.038) (0.080) (0.027)
    Year 2 0.47*** 0.39*** 0.25*** 0.26*** 0.39***
(0.081) (0.078) (0.055) (0.073) (0.035)
    Year 3 0.37*** 0.31*** 0.45*** 0.40*** 0.40***
(0.066) (0.060) (0.058) (0.10) (0.029)
    Year 4 0.61*** 0.66*** 0.59*** 0.69*** 0.62***
(0.058) (0.058) (0.047) (0.066) (.023)

N (terms) 25 25 25 25
R-squared 0.926 0.923 0.924 0.889
SER 0.65 0.65 0.48 0.72
N (participants) 64 47 68 74 307

% weight on 4th year over 1st year 217%*** 300%*** 197%*** 627%*** 270%***
% weight on 4th year over 3rd year 165%*** 212%*** 131%*** 173%*** 155%***
Standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
 

End bias with retrospective evaluations of crime prevention
To see whether these results generalize to other domains, I replicated the second term experiment with murder rates. I followed the same procedures except I labeled the axes as percent change in murders committed and told participants that these were hypothetical second term governors, not presidents. Participants saw 25 terms and the murder growth rates were drawn from a normal distribution with a mean and standard deviation equal to two. Figure 4 presents an example of one of these plots.
Instead of asking respondents about the economy, I asked, “How would you rate this governor's crime prevention record during this period? Is it very good, fairly good, fairly bad, or very bad?” To put murder growth and these evaluations on a similar scale, I recoded responses to vary from 0 to 10, with 10 corresponding to “very bad.” I then take the average of the responses for each of the 25 terms.
Table 4 regresses the average evaluation on each year's murder growth rate. Once again, end bias is evident. In fact, results are somewhat stronger than for income growth.  Participants place many times more weight on the last year (b = .76) than on the second year (b = .12) or first year (b = -.05).

 
Figure 4: Example from murder rate experiment


 

Table 4: When evaluating hypothetical murder rate changes during the four-year terms, participants exhibit end bias
Simulated murder data (25 four-year terms). Dependent variable: How would you rate this governor's crime prevention record during this period?  Is it very good, fairly good, fairly bad, or very bad? Is it very good, fairly good, fairly bad, or very bad? To put murder growth and these evaluations on a similar scale, I recoded responses to vary from 0 to 10, with 10 corresponding to “very bad” I take the average of the responses for each of the 25 terms.
DV: Four-year crime prevention evaluations (1)
Randomly drawn murder data
Murder % change
    Year 1 -0.050
(0.068)
    Year 2 0.12**
(0.054)
    Year 3 0.35***
(0.062)
    Year 4 0.76***
(0.069)

N (terms) 25
R-squared 0.912
SER 0.60
N (participants) 36
Standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

End bias with retrospective evaluations of real-world income data
 In this section, I show that people are equally myopic when viewing real-world income data from presidents’ actual terms, instead of simulated data. Moreover, their myopia closely resembles voters’ actual response to this income growth in the 1944-2008 elections, a finding that adds external validity to these lab-like studies.
Before describing and presenting the real-world studies, I first show voters’ actual response to income growth in 1944-2008 presidential elections.  In the first column of Table 5, I regress the incumbent party's popular vote margin on income growth in each year of the four-year terms. This regression provides us with a baseline against which we can compare participants’ behavior. Consistent with previous work, the election-year economy (Year 4) has a pronounced and statistically significant effect on voting (b = 4.37, p <.01). Each percentage point of election-year income growth increases the incumbent party’s expected margin by 4.4 percentage points. In contrast, third year growth has a much smaller effect (b = 1.48), which is not statistically significant at conventional levels. First and second year growth are slightly negatively related to vote margin, but essentially just zero. For whatever reason, citizens, mostly neglect all but the final year economy.
Do observers behave equally myopically with real-world data? Do they behave like citizens? To see whether they do, I showed participants yearly income growth for these 17 terms, the same data used in the vote-margin regression. I again presented these as hypothetical presidents in their second terms.  Below each plot, I once more asked, “How would you rate the condition of the national economy during this period? Is it very good, fairly good, fairly bad, or very bad?” I again recode responses to vary from 0 to 10, with 10 corresponding to “very good,” take the average response to each of the 17 terms, and call this variable Economic evaluations.
When presented with the real-world data, people responded in the now familiar myopic pattern. Column 2 regresses Economic evaluations on income growth in each year. The pattern of coefficients closely resembles those for the simulated data. More importantly, the pattern resembles that for actual vote share in these elections. Since the incumbent vote share margin (the Column 1 DV) and Economic evaluations (the Column 2 DV) are on different scales, the similarity is not as clear as it could be. To address this, Columns 3 and 4 present the same regressions after recoding both DVs to vary between 0 and 1. Once recoded, this similarity is obvious. Fourth year income growth, for instance, has effect of .13 on Incumbent vote margin and .12 on Economic evaluations. Participants thus place less and less weight on earlier year's income growth, as do voters, with the first year being slightly negatively related to Economic evaluations, as it is for voters as well.
Given that real-world voters and lab participants respond so similarly to the same data, lab participants’ evaluations of the economy should predict actual voting quite well. Figure 5 shows that they do. It plots the incumbent party's popular vote margin against the average of valuation of the economy. Even though they thought these were hypothetical, second-term presidents, they nevertheless predict the actual election margins with surprising accuracy. By showing that observers exhibit the same behavior as voters, these findings further support the end-bias explanation for myopic economic voting.
Of course, people's focus on election-year income growth in the lab could arise for reasons having nothing to do what with why voters focus on election-year income growth in the real-world. In particular, the focus on the final year could be simple laziness. People may rush through the plots and only remember what they saw last, which might be fourth year growth. To address this alternative, I conducted an experiment where I displayed the income growth with horizontal bars, instead of vertical bars. The study had two conditions. In the normal condition, the bars were in descending order, with Year 1 at the top and Year 4 at the bottom. In the reversed condition, I flipped the bars, so participants saw Year 4 at the top and Year 1 at the bottom. Figure 6 presents examples of these plots. If the lab myopia reflected merely a visual error, the myopia should disappear (or reverse) in the reversed condition. As the right two columns of Table 5 show, however, the myopic pattern shows up in both conditions.



 


Table 5: Participants respond to plots of real-world income data in the same way voters do to actual income growth
1941-2008
17 four-year presidential terms
(subjects told these were hypothetical, 2nd-term pres.) Replication
1949-2008
15 four-year terms
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
DVs rescaled 0 and 1 Horizontal bars Horizontal reversed
DV: Actual inc. vote margin Econ. eval. Inc. vote margin Econ. eval. Econ. eval.
Income growth %
    Year 1 -0.032 -0.065 -0.00093 -0.0098 0.16*** 0.19***
(0.70) (0.063) (0.021) (0.0095) (0.028) (0.039)
    Year 2 -0.43 0.24*** -0.013 0.036*** 0.29*** 0.34***
(0.70) (0.063) (0.021) (0.0095) (0.033) (0.039)
    Year 3 1.48 0.47*** 0.044 0.071*** 0.17*** 0.17***
(0.94) (0.084) (0.028) (0.013) (0.034) (0.053)
    Year 4 4.37*** 0.77*** 0.13*** 0.12*** 0.48*** 0.50***
(1.07) (0.096) (0.032) (0.015) (0.060) (0.072)

N (terms) 17 17 17 17 15 15
R-squared 0.640 0.916 0.640 0.916 0.949 0.933
SER 7.32 0.66 0.22 0.099 0.052 0.063
N (participants) NA 64 NA 64
Standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1


 
Figure 5: Participants’ evaluations of the yearly income growth predicts the election margins of actual presidential elections with surprising accuracy






    
Figure 6: Examples of plots from the horizontal-bar vs. horizontal-reversed experiment
 
Further evidence that it's not because the fourth year is more informative
As noted above, an alternative explanation for myopic retrospective economic voting is that participants believe later years are more informative about the presidents’ performance. Several facts, however, suggests that this interpretation is unlikely. First, similar patterns show up in numerous psychology studies even when the end is not more informative, such as in the cold water trials or in observers’ evaluations of other people's experience listening to loud drilling noises (Varey and Kahneman 1992).
Second, in economic cases, the evaluation question used in the studies above asked, not about the presidents’ performance, but about “the conditions of the national economy during this period?” So, a literal reading of the question should not elicit considerations about policy lags (though the context may have triggered them).
Third, participants are apparently unaware of the extent to which they upweight later years. Right after participants rated the four-year periods in the second-term, simulated income study, I asked them, “When evaluating the economy during these four-year periods, how much weight did you give to each year?” I then instructed participants to record a percent for each year with the total summing to 100% (the survey showed respondents the sum as they entered the weights). As Table 6 shows, participants report giving each year roughly equal weight, though the averages do increase a bit: 19.3%, 23.2%, 28.4%, and 29.5%, for the first through fourth years, respectively. Compared to the greater attention actually given to later years, these differences are small. Participants only report placing about (29.5%/19.3%/ =) 50% more weight on the fourth year relative to the first year, but they actually place (.62/.23*100 =) 270% more, based on the average of the simulated-data studies (see Table 3). Of course, these weights are not necessarily comparable, but the differences still seem striking. I have rerun this question several times, finding the same results.
To further test whether respondents down weight earlier years because of policy lags, I conducted another study in which participants evaluated simulated income growth data over much longer periods. I randomly assigned participants to see two versions of the 25 yearly-income-growth plots. In a four-year condition, respondents saw plots just like those shown above, except I told them that the plots showed yearly income growth in a state for a hypothetical governor’s term, instead of a hypothetical president’s term.  In the four-term condition, I told participants that the plots showed the average income growth in each term for governors with especially long tenures: four terms, each of four years. I left the plots exactly the same except I retitled them and relabeled the four income growth bars, not as years 1-4, but as terms 1-4. (See Appendix for examples.) If a basic cognitive bias gives rise to myopia, I expect participants to weight up later terms as much as they up weight up later years. Of course, up weighting later terms could be reasonable, assuming very long policy lags, but up weighting them to the same extent that they up weight later years in a four-year term seems unreasonable. As expected, participants behave equally myopically with four-terms as they do with four years. The Appendix presents the results. In short, this experiment provides yet further evidence that myopia reflects a cognitive bias, not a deliberate strategy.

 

Table 6: Self-reported weights on income growth
When evaluating the economy during these four-year periods, how much weight did you give to each year? (Please enter a percent for each year, with the total summing to 100%.)
Means Medians
Year 1 19.3 20
(0.87) (1.46)
Year 2 23.9 25
(0.95) (0.97)
Year 3 27.4 25
(0.74) (0.97)
Year 4 29.9 25
(1.32) (2.11)
Standard errors in parentheses.

Curing end bias
All told, these studies suggest that end bias gives rise to myopic retrospective voting on the economy and in other domains. Given the costs of myopia — adverse selection and dead weight loss — I now search for a cure.
As noted above, one explanation for end bias is attribute substitution (Kahneman 2003; Kahneman and Frederick 2002). When engaging in intuitive, low effort judgments, people often substitute a salient attribute for the desired one. Based on self-reports, people think each year should be weighted roughly equally, with slightly more weight given to later years on average (see Table 6). They thus probably desire to base their judgments more or less on total growth during the terms, especially for second term incumbents.  Since strong economic performance should lead to more total growth at the end, they may, without realizing it, substitute election-year growth for total growth. If so, presenting plots that more readily reveal total growth should cure them of myopia.
To explore this possibility, I conducted an experiment with two conditions. In the control condition, participants saw yearly growth plots, just like those shown above. In the treatment condition, participants saw both yearly growth and a cumulative growth (one on top of the other). Figure 7 presents an example. The cumulative growth plot simply adds up the current and prior year growth. Although somewhat awkward, the figures nevertheless allow participants to choose between yearly growth and cumulative growth.  In the instructions for the study, I provided a brief explanation of how cumulative growth relates to yearly growth, an explanation I also included in each cumulative plot.  The study had 25 terms and used simulated data as described above.
When presented with this choice, do people focus on cumulative growth? That is, do they choose to cure their myopia? To test whether they do, Table 7 shows estimates of the weight given to each years’ income growth when evaluating the four-year economy. The results are dramatic. When participants saw the standard plot, the end mattered more, as in the studies above. When participants saw both the yearly and cumulative plots, however, they gave roughly equal weight to each year. The difference in weights is most dramatic for the first year: b = .12 in the yearly growth condition versus b = .44 in the cumulative condition.    
A problem with this cure is that cumulative plots are complicated. Another approach to achieving the same goal is, instead of showing people percent change, which seems to trip them up, show levels in the relevant units, such as per capita income in dollars in each year of a term. To test whether this would also cure myopia, I picked the previous income growth experiment with the greatest end bias, which was in a gubernatorial study (see Column 4, Table 3). I then tried to cure it by using its randomly drawn income growth data to generate level data. Figure 8 presents an example of a level plot. For the first year of each term, I drew an initial value from a normal distribution with a mean of about $32,000, which is the average RDI since 2000 and a standard deviation of 100. To keep the study as similar as possible, I only showed one bar for each year of the term, which only allows participants to see income growth between three years.
As with the cumulative plot, the level-in-dollars plot also appears to cure myopia. Column 3 of Table 7 reproduces the original yearly finding of end bias while Column 4 presents the estimates for the level study. Although we cannot compare the first year, the weight participants place on the second year increases substantially, from b = .26 to b = .54, a difference that is highly statistically significant, while the weight they place on last year decreases. In fact, participants in the level study put more weight on the second year than they do on the fourth year (b = .54 versus b = .46). Figure 9 shows this finding visually by plotting average responses against income growth in each year.
Further experiments are needed, but these results are promising. They suggest that curing myopia in retrospective evaluations may be easy.


 
Figure 7: Example of cumulative condition

 
 
Figure 8: Examples of income-level-in-dollars plots


Table 7: The cures.
Showing individuals cumulative income growth data or showing people income in levels appears to cure myopia.
Cumulative growth experiment Level growth experiment
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Yearly income growth plots Cumulative & yearly income plots Yearly income plots Income level plots
Income growth %
    Year 1 0.12* 0.44*** 0.11
(0.060) (0.063) (0.080)
    Year 2 0.37*** 0.50*** 0.26*** 0.54***
(0.053) (0.056) (0.073) (0.067)
    Year 3 0.46*** 0.54*** 0.40*** 0.37***
(0.058) (0.061) (0.10) (0.053)
    Year 4 0.59*** 0.50*** 0.69*** 0.42***
(0.040) (0.042) (0.066) (0.061)

N (terms) 25 25 25 25
R-squared 0.937 0.936 0.889 0.923
SER 0.47 0.49 0.72 0.60
N (participants) 54 62 74 47
Note: Standard errors in parentheses. Constant not shown. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
 
 
Figure 9: A cure. Scatter plots for the income in levels experiment.
When participants see income levels in dollars (bottom plot), they exhibit less end bias than when they see only yearly percent growth (top plot). The effects are largest for Year 2 (effects for Year 1 can't be estimated)

 
Conclusions
Retrospective voting assumes citizens are competent evaluators of incumbent politicians' performance. In this paper, I presented evidence that an end bias generally affects retrospective assessments. When citizens judge incumbent performance on issues such as the economy or crime, their experiences at the end of terms appear to shape their memories of earlier performance.
Using a three-year panel survey, I showed that citizens' memories of the past economy are inconsistent with their actual experience of the economy as they reported it in earlier panel waves. They fail to remember the past correctly in part because the present shapes their perceptions of the past.
I then showed similar behavior in the lab. When participants evaluate economic and crime data, I again found that election-year performance shapes perceptions of overall performance, even under conditions where the election year should not be more informative (second terms).
Finally, I appear to find a cure. Presenting participants with cumulative information on performance (e.g., total income growth) cures myopia. On one hand, these results are troubling for democracy because they confirm citizens’ incompetence at retrospection. On the other hand, they point to a remedy, one that candidates and the news media could adopt.

Enjoy! Let me know when you're done with this one (it demonstrates that voters can't assess historical performance very well) and I'll queue up the next one (it's about how most voters form opinions based on superficial factors.)

 

Offline General Battuta

  • Poe's Law In Action
  • 214
  • i wonder when my postcount will exceed my iq
Just as Obama campaigned on "Change", the GOP won this midterm election on "Change".

This in particular is a popular myth, incredibly pervasive but also probably wrong.

Data suggests that with rare exceptions, campaigns don't matter. Everything you hear about on the media - attack ads, debate outcomes - are pretty much irrelevant.

Political scientists can predict the outcome of elections months in advance using only data on the economy. Who's running, what they say and how they act is pretty unimportant compared to the fundamentals. The only time campaigns seem to really matter are when a big scandal kicks in, or, possibly, if one group can wildly outspend the other.

  

Offline MP-Ryan

  • Makes General Discussion Make Sense.
  • Global Moderator
  • 210
  • Keyboard > Pen > Sword
Let's concede your argument about deregulation for the moment.  Do you then say that the bankers bear absolutely no blame for the actions that followed?

Absolutely not.  The bankers caused the crisis - deregulation gave them the tools to do it with.  Both parties are equally culpable - financial institutions for engaging in practices that were virtually guaranteed to cause eventual systemic failure, and the political move by giving them the ability to do so for ideological purposes in the face of economic realities.

Quote
If there are two ways to take advantage of deregulation -- one positive way, with integrity, and one selfish way, with greed and short-sightedness -- and if a banker chooses greed over integrity, is he completely innocent?  Even if he willfully chooses to enrich himself, his colleagues, and his profession at the expense of the economy and the general population?

Here's the trouble - financial leaders in the private sector are expected to make the most money in the fastest way possible for their shareholders.  This nonsensical position of proponents of a completely de-regulated free market ignores one fundamental truth about humanity:  people are not primarily motivated, but by Darwinian competition.  It's written into our behaviour as a species.  Yes, altruistic qualities are present and enable us to function as a society, but our behaviour is oriented toward individual success; more so in a free-market society than any other.

Market forces are not always stabilizing and self-regulating, just as people are not always self-regulating in their behaviour.  It takes social links to keep us behaving within socially-defined limits.  Without those links, our default state is self-oriented.  The same is true of corporations - as large entities driven by a particular set of fundamental motivations and lacking in a collective consciousness to impose morality, they require regulation in order to establish those socially-defined limits.  Where individuals are bound by unwritten rules within a society because of their ability to perceive social rules, large collective entities lack this ability (the formal term for this is 'groupthink,' which is defined slightly differently in social psychology than in lay terms.  I wrote a paper on it a few years back.)

Individual corporations make buck this trend on the individual merits of their leaders from time to time, but even that is rare.  When a corporation with a motto of "Don't be evil" still manages to do so purely by accident because of the lack of a collective consciousness, it's pretty clear that regulation in some form is always going to be required.  When that's missing, we can hardly expect corporations without that collective consciousness or morality to abide by rules that are not defined and lack consequences when their motivating purpose is to achieve an end in the most expedient way possible.

TL;DR version:

The financial sector and politicians who de-regulated it are equally as culpable in the recession.  However, as the public has a very short collective memory and a poor understanding of the interaction between politics and economics in general (Presidents have virtually no impact on economics as a whole), that was promptly forgotten this election, as is quite evident from the results.
"In the beginning, the Universe was created.  This made a lot of people very angry and has widely been regarded as a bad move."  [Douglas Adams]